Misunderstanding Reserve Currencies and the Gold Standard

In Friday’s Wall Street Journal, Lewis Lehrman and John Mueller argue for replacing the dollar as the world’s reserve currency with gold. I don’t know Lewis Lehrman, but almost 30 years ago, when I was writing my book Free Banking and Monetary Reform, which opposed restoring the gold standard, I received financial support from the Lehrman Institute where I gave a series of seminars discussing several chapters of my book. A couple of those seminars were attended by John Mueller, who was then a staffer for Congressman Jack Kemp. But despite my friendly feelings for Lehrman and Mueller, I am afraid that they badly misunderstand how the gold standard worked and what went wrong with the gold standard in the 1920s. Not surprisingly, that misunderstanding carries over into their comments on current monetary arrangements.

Lehrman and Mueller begin by discussing the 1922 Genoa Conference, a conference largely inspired by the analysis of Ralph Hawtrey and Gustav Cassel of post-World War I monetary conditions, and by their proposals for restoring an international gold standard without triggering a disastrous deflation in the process of doing so, the international price level in terms of gold having just about doubled relative to the pre-War price level.

The 1922 Genoa conference, which was intended to supervise Europe’s post-World War I financial reconstruction, recommended “some means of economizing the use of gold by maintaining reserves in the form of foreign balances”—initially pound-sterling and dollar IOUs. This established the interwar “gold exchange standard.”

Lehrman and Mueller then cite the view of the gold exchange standard expressed by the famous French economist Jacques Rueff, of whom Lehrman is a fervent admirer.

A decade later Jacques Rueff, an influential French economist, explained the result of this profound change from the classical gold standard. When a foreign monetary authority accepts claims denominated in dollars to settle its balance-of-payments deficits instead of gold, purchasing power “has simply been duplicated.” If the Banque de France counts among its reserves dollar claims (and not just gold and French francs)—for example a Banque de France deposit in a New York bank—this increases the money supply in France but without reducing the money supply of the U.S. So both countries can use these dollar assets to grant credit. “As a result,” Rueff said, “the gold-exchange standard was one of the major causes of the wave of speculation that culminated in the September 1929 crisis.” A vast expansion of dollar reserves had inflated the prices of stocks and commodities; their contraction deflated both.

This is astonishing. Lehrman and Mueller do not identify the publication of Rueff that they are citing, but I don’t doubt the accuracy of the quotation. What Rueff is calling for is a 100% marginal reserve requirement. Now it is true that under the Bank Charter Act of 1844, Great Britain had a 100% marginal reserve requirement on Bank of England notes, but throughout the nineteenth century, there was an shift from banknotes to bank deposits, so the English money supply was expanding far more rapidly than English gold reserves. The kind of monetary system that Rueff was talking about, in which the quantity of money in circulation, could not increase by more than the supply of gold, never existed. Money was being created under the gold standard without an equal amount of gold being held in reserve.

The point of the gold exchange standard, after World War I, was to economize on the amount of gold held by central banks as they rejoined the gold standard to prevent a deflation back to the pre-War price level. Gold had been demonetized over the course of World War I as countries used gold to pay for imports, much of it winding up in the US before the US entered the war. If all the demonetized gold was remonetized, the result would be a huge rise in the value of gold, in other words, a huge, catastrophic, deflation.

Nor does the notion that the gold-exchange standard was the cause of speculation that culminated in the 1929 crisis have any theoretical or evidentiary basis. Interest rates in the 1920s were higher than they ever were during the heyday of the classical gold standard from about 1880 to 1914. Prices were not rising faster in the 1920s than they did for most of the gold standard era, so there is no basis for thinking that speculation was triggered by monetary causes. Indeed, there is no basis for thinking that there was any speculative bubble in the 1920s, or that even if there was such a bubble it was triggered by monetary expansion. What caused the 1929 crash was not the bursting of a speculative bubble, as taught by the popular mythology of the crash, it was caused by the sudden increase in the demand for gold in 1928 and 1929 resulting from the insane policy of the Bank of France and the clueless policy of the Federal Reserve after ill health forced Benjamin Strong to resign as President of the New York Fed.

Lehrman and Mueller go on to criticize the Bretton Woods system.

The gold-exchange standard’s demand-duplicating feature, based on the dollar’s reserve-currency role, was again enshrined in the 1944 Bretton Woods agreement. What ensued was an unprecedented expansion of official dollar reserves, and the consumer price level in the U.S. and elsewhere roughly doubled. Foreign governments holding dollars increasingly demanded gold before the U.S. finally suspended gold payments in 1971.

The gold-exchange standard of the 1920s was a real gold standard, but one designed to minimize the monetary demand for gold by central banks. In the 1920s, the US and Great Britain were under a binding obligation to convert dollars or pound sterling on demand into gold bullion, so there was a tight correspondence between the value of gold and the price level in any country maintaining a fixed exchange rate against the dollar or pound sterling. Under Bretton Woods, only the US was obligated to convert dollars into gold, but the obligation was largely a fiction, so the tight correspondence between the value of gold and the price level no longer obtained.

The economic crisis of 2008-09 was similar to the crisis that triggered the Great Depression. This time, foreign monetary authorities had purchased trillions of dollars in U.S. public debt, including nearly $1 trillion in mortgage-backed securities issued by two government-sponsored enterprises, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. The foreign holdings of dollars were promptly returned to the dollar market, an example of demand duplication. This helped fuel a boom-and-bust in foreign markets and U.S. housing prices. The global excess credit creation also spilled over to commodity markets, in particular causing the world price of crude oil (which is denominated in dollars) to spike to $150 a barrel.

There were indeed similarities between the 1929 crisis and the 2008 crisis. In both cases, the world financial system was made vulnerable because there was a lot of bad debt out there. In 2008, it was subprime mortgages, in 1929 it was reckless borrowing by German local governments and the debt sold to refinance German reparations obligations under the Treaty of Versailles. But in neither episode did the existence of bad debt have anything to do with monetary policy; in both cases tight monetary policy precipitated a crisis that made a default on the bad debt unavoidable.

Lehrman and Mueller go on to argue, as do some Keynesians like Jared Bernstein, that the US would be better off if the dollar were not a reserve currency. There may be disadvantages associated with having a reserve currency – disadvantages like those associated with having a large endowment of an exportable natural resource, AKA the Dutch disease – but the only way for the US to stop having a reserve currency would be to take a leaf out of the Zimbabwe hyperinflation playbook. Short of a Zimbabwean hyperinflation, the network externalities internalized by using the dollar as a reserve currency are so great, that the dollar is likely to remain the world’s reserve currency for at least a millennium. Of course, the flip side of the Dutch disease is at that there is a wealth transfer from the rest of the world to the US – AKA seignorage — in exchange for using the dollar.

Lehrman and Mueller are aware of the seignorage accruing to the supplier of a reserve currency, but confuse the collection of seignorage with the benefit to the world as a whole of minimizing the use of gold as the reserve currency. This leads them to misunderstand the purpose of the Genoa agreement, which they mistakenly attribute to Keynes, who actually criticized the agreement in his Tract on Monetary Reform.

This was exactly what Keynes and other British monetary experts promoted in the 1922 Genoa agreement: a means by which to finance systemic balance-of-payments deficits, forestall their settlement or repayment and put off demands for repayment in gold of Britain’s enormous debts resulting from financing World War I on central bank and foreign credit. Similarly, the dollar’s “exorbitant privilege” enabled the U.S. to finance government deficit spending more cheaply.

But we have since learned a great deal that Keynes did not take into consideration. As Robert Mundell noted in “Monetary Theory” (1971), “The Keynesian model is a short run model of a closed economy, dominated by pessimistic expectations and rigid wages,” a model not relevant to modern economies. In working out a “more general theory of interest, inflation, and growth of the world economy,” Mr. Mundell and others learned a great deal from Rueff, who was the master and professor of the monetary approach to the balance of payments.

The benefit from supplying the resource that functions as the world’s reserve currency will accrue to someone, that is the “exorbitant privilege” to which Lehrman and Mueller refer. But It is not clear why it would be better if the privilege accrued to owners of gold instead of to the US Treasury. On the contrary, the potential for havoc associated with reinstating gold as the world’s reserve currency dwarfs the “exorbitant privilege.” Nor is the reference to Keynes relevant to the discussion, the Keynesian model described by Mundell being the model of the General Theory, which was certainly not the model that Keynes was working with at the time of the Genoa agreement in which Keynes’s only involvement was as an outside critic.

As for Rueff, staunch defender of the insane policy of the Bank of France in 1932, he was an estimable scholar, but, luckily, his influence was much less than Lehrman and Mueller suggest.

15 Responses to “Misunderstanding Reserve Currencies and the Gold Standard”


  1. 1 lewisb2014 November 22, 2014 at 7:54 pm

    Really excellent post, David. Your point on seignorage as essentially a payment for the services of running a reserve currency is a great one. It’s one we don’t remind our population of adequately. And unfortunately, when I’ve read pieces like the one in the Journal by those fixated on returning to gold, I’ve also found them pretty off-target, with explanations that don’t exhibit much understanding of the issues historically or currently.

    There are several aspects of our running of the reserve currency that I don’t see mentioned much by those yearning for a return to gold, or even some commenting generally on monetary matters. E.g.:

    We have been willing to take current account deficits, which most other major countries constantly (and for reasons I and many other economists find partly irrational: they essentially prefer to produce more and give it to others in exchange for electronic entries) want not to have. Consider the number of major countries (start with Germany, and it has lots of company) that constantly want to run current account surpluses. Such behavior requires someone on the other side. The biggest someone has consistently been the U.S., for most of the last 35 years. And of course, the capital and current account surpluses offset: the U.S. gets inflows of foreign capital and has relatively few restrictions on it. I think in general that our willingness to take the current account deficits that few others take willingly is one of the reasons we remain the reserve currency issuer–and get compensated for it as you point out.

    We were the ones that got the point first that the world needed adequate liquidity during the Global Financial Crisis. (In fairness, the ECB did provide some. But as we know, the Eurozone also has embedded in its architecture a fiscal structure that was a disaster in coping with a severe recession, and remains so.) Acting as a lender of last resort is a valuable service that many other countries would not be willing to render–or wouldn’t be able to do while keeping inflation relatively low.

    The U.S. has had relatively open capital markets. Many others have not, at least at times when it suited them to restrict their openness.

    And the gold standard kept a degree of long-run stability by a very wasteful mechanism. Deflation raises the price of gold and thereby sends a price signal to produce more . . . and since we don’t use gold coins (they have long been far too valuable for day-to-day transactions) we mostly put the monetary gold back in the ground. The price of that stability is a large use of resources that does nothing but serve as a backing for money. If we can keep relative price stability without doing that, it’s a clear social gain.

    In his book Money Mischief, published in the early 1990s, Friedman described the “almost surely negative” welfare effects of gold discoveries–unless a gold standard was necessary as a nominal anchor. In fact, in his chapter 1 entitled “The Island of Stone Money,” which chronicled the Yap islanders use of stone fei, he commented:

    “The Yap islanders regarded as a concrete manifestation of their wealth stones quarried and shaped on a distant island and brought to their own. For a century and more, the civilized world regarded as a concrete manifestation of its wealth a metal dug from deep in the ground, refined at great labor, transported great distances, and buried again in elaborate vaults deep in the ground. Is the one practice really more rational than the other?”

    Fiat money is one the great social innovations of all time–and it goes back a long way. Figuring out how to control and use it has been a big benefit to us.

    Like

  2. 2 Auburn Parks November 22, 2014 at 7:58 pm

    WRT the status of the US dollar being the main reserve currency, what other state currency is large enough to run the requisite trade deficits necessary for foreigners to accumulate enough of said currency?

    Every major state currency nation(s) is\are doing their best to run trade surpluses in order to achieve the necessary aggregate demand to employ their domestic populations. Except for the USA (thankfully). now if only we could get the Govt to enact policies that supplement our aggregate demand, we’d be in good shape.

    WRT the cause of the Great Depression, if your position is that there was no bubble preceding the crash, then what is your response to the private debt levels as a % of GDP leading up to 1929:

    Like

  3. 3 lewisb2014 November 22, 2014 at 8:16 pm

    Great post, David. I especially liked your point on seignorage as a payment for providing/managing a reserve currency that has incredible externalities.
    I find articles like the one you critiqued very frustrating as they don’t seem often to have a grasp of either the current or historical issues connected wit the gold standard.

    Three points with respect to the U.S. and its reserve currency, I think, deserve emphasis:

    1. Most major countries (start with Germany but there’s plenty of company) want to run current account surpluses. The world as a whole can’t. The U.S. has regularly, for most of the last 35 years, been the country willing to take the other side by running current account deficits. Would most countries like to make the euro the reserve currency?

    2. The other part of the balance of payments equalities is that the current and capital accounts offset. We also have relatively open capital markets (some others do not) and allow foreigners to invest relatively easily in U.S. financial and real assets. Our current account deficits are offset by this investment, but some other countries are not so ready to allow a varied menu of investment options.

    3. The U.S. was the lender of last resort in the Global Financial Crisis; the ECB did provide some liquidity but as we know, the Eurozone architecture with its fiscal deficit limits has been a major problem. U.S. willingness to take on the role it did is part of the reason we’re a reserve currency.

    I also find it useful to consider what Milton Friedman thought about the gold standard. In his book Money Mischief written in the early 1990s, he described the “almost surely negative” welfare effects of gold discoveries but went on to comment that “the world is now engaged in a great experiment to see if it can fashion a different [nominal] anchor [than gold], one that depends on government restraint rather than on the cost of acquiring a physical commodity.” He recognized the burden of a gold standard in terms of its cost–but that burden, he thought, might be necessary.

    I think of it as the paradox of the gold standard. The so-called long-term price stability of the gold standard (we had, of course, a long deflation followed by an inflation in the late 19th century) comes at a major cost: during a deflation, the market is sending a message that it’s worth more real resources per ounce to find and refine gold, and the market obliges. That eventually stops the deflation, but at a very significant resource cost. Fiat money costs very little but requires discipline.

    Friedman also had a statement I don’t see quoted much by those in favor of a return to gold. In the first chapter of Money Mischief he described the use for money of large stone fei by the Yap islanders. He went on to comment toward the end of that chapter:

    “The Yap islanders regarded as a concrete manifestation of their wealth stones quarried and shaped on a distant island and brought to their own. For a century and more, the civilized world regarded as a concrete manifestation of its wealth a metal dug from deep in the ground, refined at great labour, transported great distances, and buried again in elaborate vaults deep in the ground. Is the one practice really more rational than the other?”

    I’d love to see Lew Lehrman’s answer.

    Fiat money managed well enough to keep inflation at a reasonably low rate without the waste of resources of a commodity standard is one of our great social innovations, and it’s been used in a lot of situations for a long time.

    Like

  4. 4 Benjamin Cole November 22, 2014 at 9:18 pm

    My grandfather said it best: “All gold is fool’s gold.”

    Like

  5. 5 NeilW November 23, 2014 at 1:20 am

    “and for reasons I and many other economists find partly irrational”

    It’s not that irrational. Apparently it is more acceptable to ship real things that you have spent time to produce and create to other countries so that they will give you their currency that you can’t use in your country, which you then have to swap out in the banking system with your own currency, than it is to inject your own currency in the first place, run a state deficit and have a higher standard of living.

    The problem is net saving – which is permitted by the system and generally encouraged. Something has to offset that paradox of thrift.

    The push for net exports solves that problem in a way that those who are hard of accounting find acceptable.

    The smart country prepared to run constant accounting deficits and not worry about it automatically gets a higher standard of living in payment.

    See it as a service to those countries who believe a strange old-time religion. Germany being the biggest victim, although of course they have found a way of convincing a whole host of other countries to take the pain instead.

    Like

  6. 6 JMRJ November 23, 2014 at 8:05 am

    I agree this is an excellent post, not least because the word “seigniorage” appears in it, but I must submit it’s economists who misunderstand the gold standard, probably because the gold standard is a matter of law, not economics.

    I wrote a little about seigniorage almost three years ago:

    “Plain Money” And “Seigniorage Reform”

    You economist types might peruse the following post and a few that come after it:

    Saving The World, Revised Edition, Part I

    Basically the idea is a jubilee – decreed by law – followed by a return to a gold standard managed by the central bank in much the same way as the central bank now manages interest rates. The latter is a significant modification of my original thoughts on the subject (if that matters to anyone other than me), where I advocated abolishing the central bank.

    I think you are all quite wrong that a gold standard inevitably leads to deflation. There may be good social reasons to treat the dollar definition differently from other weights and measures, but renouncing redeemability entirely cannot help but lead to tyranny, as it has both in the US and elsewhere.

    Fundamentally, I think what is missing from your collective perspectives is the realization that the law has to govern, not economic theories. I appreciate that the legal profession has essentially abdicated to economists in that regard, but of course things don’t have to stay that way.

    And the claim that the dollar will remain the “reserve currency” for at least a millennium is very revealing. Many social conditions (war and revolution come immediately to mind) trump any kind of “economic policy”. Economic policy can be a tool of government, not the foundation of government itself. I suppose it’s not a coincidence that your views ultimately translate into the very high status and influence economists currently enjoy, but in the end the question is whether economists rule, or the rule of law governs them like everyone else.

    Nothing trumps natural law, and that’s what the gold standard is, and that’s in the final analysis why it is so bitterly opposed by economists.

    I would appreciate, by the way, any opinions anyone reading here would have on the proposal I have made for a jubilee/gold standard, the details of which are found through the previous links. Always good to consider other opinions.

    Like

  7. 7 Peter Schaeffer November 23, 2014 at 12:37 pm

    This is a very good article that I (generally) strongly agree with. However, the article contains two statements that are so wrong (in my opinion) that they detract from the strength of the overall argument. They author writes

    “Indeed, there is no basis for thinking that there was any speculative bubble in the 1920s”

    The evidence for a bubble in the 1920s is actually rather strong. The online Shiller data is a good starting point. The S&P Composite rose by almost 50% in the year before the crash (from 21.17 in 9/1928 to 31.30 in 9/29). The Shiller P/E ratio rose from 17.82 in 9/1927 to 32.56 in 9/1929. Note that it was below 10 in 7/1925.

    The DJIA tells a similar story. The DJIA peaked at 381.17 on 9/3/1929. It was only 240.24 on 9/4/1928 and 191.26 on 9/3/1927. Note that the DJIA was just below 100 on 7/25/1925.

    The fantastic rise in stock prices and P/E ratios was not matched by a comparable growth in corporate earnings. Earnings in 9/1929 ($1.55) were only slightly higher than 12/1916 ($1.53). Of course, earnings in 1916 were inflated by WWI. However, earnings were around $0.90 after WWI and exceeded a dollar in 1925.

    The second objectionable statement is

    “Short of a Zimbabwean hyperinflation, the network externalities internalized by using the dollar as a reserve currency are so great, that the dollar is likely to remain the world’s reserve currency for at least a millennium.”

    No reserve currency has lasted more than a few hundred years (at most). Moreover, reserve currency status and overall economic power can’t be separated. The dollar became the reserve currency of the world because the U.S. had the largest economy. Yes, there was a rather long lag separating U.S. economic dominance (greatest GDP) which started in the 1870s and reserve currency status (beginning in the 1920s). However, the linkage is pretty clear. It is also true that reserve currency status is also associated with capital exports, not gigantic debts and deficits (trade, budget, etc.).

    The EU and China now exceed the U.S. in total GDP. India will pass the U.S. economically eventually (decades). Is it really plausible that the 4th largest economy in the world will still have the dominant reserve currency in 50 years?

    At present, China’s economy is too closed and the EU is too unstable for the RMB or Euro to become dominant reserve currencies any time soon. However, both conditions could change. Beyond that, the U.S. isn’t a model of sober economic management. The dollar became a reserve currency back when the U.S. had very conservative attitudes towards debt, deficits, trade, etc. See “America’s Fiscal Constitution: Its Triumph and Collapse” for a book on the subject (written by a Democrat).

    Historically America took considerable pains to protect the strength of its domestic economy. Now we have a dominant ideology of “free trade” that extolls outsourcing and “hollowing out” as virtuous (and ignores that inevitable consequences of debt proliferation). That’s not a formula for maintaining a reserve currency over the long term.

    Like

  8. 8 peterschaeffer November 23, 2014 at 1:10 pm

    As I stated earlier, this is a very good article. I would like to add one more data point, as to evils of the gold standard.

    Japan in late 1920 and in the 1930s is a case study in how gold (and the ideology of the gold standard) can lead a nation astray. The proponents of gold In Japan were liberal internationalists. They destroyed their own country with their economic theories, but they were also (no joke) liberals, free traders, democrats, and advocates of world peace.

    The tragic life and death of Junnosuke Inoue exemplifies his class. In 1929, as Minister of Finance he put Japan back on gold. In 1931 he was murdered in the League of Blood Incident.

    Their opponents were right-wing fanatical militarists. They brought down the liberal order in Japan with a war of assassination. They pushed Japan off gold and enabled very substantial economic growth in the 1930s. They also plunged Japan into unwinnable wars that led inexorably to Hiroshima.

    Like

  9. 9 Tom November 25, 2014 at 12:26 am

    I’m afraid this post really is too bent on blaming the gold standard for everything and the kitchen sink and unreasobly dismissive of the large 1920s credit bubble, which was in corporate debt and margin credit. Of course tightening set off the crisis, and also in 2007. Tightening precedes most recessions. Tightening is part of the credit cycle, and happens even when there is no central bank. Usually when the reaction to tightening is severe that’s taken as evidence that the central bank tightened too late after too many vulnerabilities had proliferated. Unless your argument is that central banks should abolish all tightening forever, I don’t really see what point you’re making about the Fed in 29.

    I think the gold standard had its upsides and downsides. I don’t see the point in getting all riled up over whether it was great or terrible. It won’t ever come back anyway, There’s a whole lot more interesting to the economic history of the gold standard era than the gold standard. And I just don’t see how anyone will ever know whether things would have gone better or worse without it.

    But the spirit of the gold standard lives on in the euro. The common thread is that people just like having a common standard, and they like the idea that the standard will be solid and predictable and rule-based, even if they somehow never quite manage that. No doubt, you see some of the same problems with the euro that the gold standard had. It sounds great until you’ve slid on the fiscal restraints for too long to restore them without a lot of pain. And yet overall Europeans prefer it over the past and won’t give it up.

    Like

  10. 10 David Glasner November 25, 2014 at 6:03 pm

    Lewis, Thanks. What serves as a reserve currency is largely the outcome of a path-dependent historical process. Like it or not, barring some cataclysm, the US is stuck with being the supplier of the world’s reserve currency. If we are smart – and our track record hardly entitles us to have a high estimate of our intelligence – we will reconcile ourselves to the role history has provided us and not try to undo what can’t be undone. I am not Friedman’s biggest fan, but I totally agree with him about the folly of digging gold out of the ground to put in central bank vaults.

    Auburn, Debt levels in 1930 don’t look like they are that much higher than in 1920. Debt levels skyrocketed after 1930 as a result of the deflation. So it was the deflation that caused debt to be excessive not excessive debt that caused the deflation.

    Benjamin, Gold is a great decoration, but way over-priced.

    Neil, It is possible to save and accumulate wealth over time. People who accumulate wealth by saving (not consuming) tend to get rich, if they buy assets that generate a decent rate of return. I don’t think that gold is a particularly good asset to hold, even though sometimes it does appreciated rapidly. If you can get the timing right, you can make a killing. Otherwise, it’s a bad investment.

    JMRJ, Law and economics are not mutually exclusive. Natural law does not exist independently of the moral arguments that can be made on behalf of those claims. People have argued that slavery is ordained by natural law and that it violates natural law. Natural law is simply a way of appealing to some external authority, but the only authority out there is the argument you can make on behalf of whatever position you are arguing for.

    My claim about the dollar remaining the world’s reserve currency for at least a millennium was just my way of saying that there is nothing on the horizon that will displace the dollar from its current position.

    Peter, The increase in stock prices in 1928-29 was anticipating the growth of earnings that would have taken place had there not been a catastrophic deflation and depression. The 1920s and 1930s was an era of rapid a technological progress and a huge increase in productivity. I don’t say that there was not some overpricing of stocks, but there was plenty of justification for stock prices to rise. About the reserve status of the dollar, see my comment to JMRJ.

    Your projections about the Chinese and Indian economies are merely projections. The point about being a reserve currency is that there are huge switching costs associated with switching from one currency to another. Those switching costs might be borne if there were an international government capable of requiring everybody switch from one currency to another, but in the absence of a deliberate agreement by everyone to switch, there would be no reason for anyone to bear those costs without an expectation that everyone else would bear those costs as well.

    Tom, I didn’t blame the ebola virus on the gold standard, so it’s not accurate to say that I blame the gold standard for everything. The Great Depression was not in any way a typical business cycle downturn, so to say that there is some tightening in every credit cycle is to misunderstand completely the chain of events that led to the Great Depression. Have a look at my posts on Hawtrey and Cassel.

    Like

  11. 11 Nensy Donovan January 10, 2015 at 1:46 pm

    The gold standard as a system developed in the middle of the XIX century. The emergence of this system was due to the need to establish trade settlements between industrial capitals of major countries.

    Like


  1. 1 Krugman’s blog, 11/28/14 | Marion in Savannah Trackback on November 29, 2014 at 5:49 am
  2. 2 Krugman: "Sticky Wages I Win, Flexible Wages You Lose" | ZombieMarkets Trackback on November 30, 2014 at 6:10 pm
  3. 3 전세계의 최신 영어뉴스 듣기 - 보이스뉴스 잉글리쉬 Trackback on November 30, 2014 at 9:56 pm
  4. 4 Krugman: "Sticky Wages I Win, Flexible Wages You Lose" - Techhic Trackback on December 1, 2014 at 6:09 am

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.




About Me

David Glasner
Washington, DC

I am an economist in the Washington DC area. My research and writing has been mostly on monetary economics and policy and the history of economics. In my book Free Banking and Monetary Reform, I argued for a non-Monetarist non-Keynesian approach to monetary policy, based on a theory of a competitive supply of money. Over the years, I have become increasingly impressed by the similarities between my approach and that of R. G. Hawtrey and hope to bring Hawtrey’s unduly neglected contributions to the attention of a wider audience.

My new book Studies in the History of Monetary Theory: Controversies and Clarifications has been published by Palgrave Macmillan

Follow me on Twitter @david_glasner

Archives

Enter your email address to follow this blog and receive notifications of new posts by email.

Join 3,272 other subscribers
Follow Uneasy Money on WordPress.com