John Cochrane Explains Neo-Fisherism

In a recent post, John Cochrane, responding to an earlier post by Nick Rowe about Neo-Fisherism, has tried to explain why raising interest rates could plausibly cause inflation to rise and reducing interest rates could plausibly cause inflation to fall, even though almost everyone, including central bankers, seems to think that when central banks raise interest rates, inflation falls, and when they reduce interest rates, inflation goes up.

In his explanation, Cochrane concedes that there is an immediate short-term tendency for increased interest rates to reduce inflation and for reduced interest rates to raise inflation, but he also argues that these effects (liquidity effects in Keynesian terminology) are transitory and would be dominated by the Fisher effects if the central bank committed itself to a permanent change in its interest-rate target. Of course, the proviso that the central bank commit itself to a permanent interest-rate peg is a pretty important qualification to the Neo-Fisherian position, because few central banks have ever committed themselves to a permanent interest-rate peg, the most famous attempt (by the Fed after World War II) to peg an interest rate having led to accelerating inflation during the Korean War, thereby forcing the peg to be abandoned, in apparent contradiction of the Neo-Fisherian view.

However, Cochrane does try to reconcile the Neo-Fisherian view with the standard view that raising interest rates reduces inflation and reducing interest rates increases inflation. He suggests that the standard view is strictly a short-run relationship and that the way to target inflation over the long-run is simply to target an interest rate consistent with the desired rate of inflation, and to rely on the Fisher equation to generate the actual and expected rate of inflation corresponding to that nominal rate. Here’s how Cochrane puts it:

We can put the issue more generally as, if the central bank does nothing to interest rates, is the economy stable or unstable following a shock to inflation?

For the next set of graphs, I imagine a shock to inflation, illustrated as the little upward sloping arrow on the left. Usually, the Fed responds by raising interest rates. What if it doesn’t?  A pure neo-Fisherian view would say inflation will come back on its own.

cochrane1

Again, we don’t have to be that pure.

The milder view allows there may be some short run dynamics; the lower real rates might lead to some persistence in inflation. But even if the Fed does nothing, eventually real interest rates have to settle down to their “natural” level, and inflation will come back. Mabye not as fast as it would if the Fed had aggressively tamed it, but eventually.

cochrane2

By contrast, the standard view says that inflation is unstable. If the Fed does not raise rates, inflation will eventually careen off following the shock.

cochrane3

Now this really confuses me. What does a shock to inflation mean? From the context, Cochrane seems to be thinking that something happens to raise the rate of inflation in the short run, but the persistence of increased inflation somehow depends on an underlying assumption about whether the economy is stable or unstable. Cochrane doesn’t tell us what kind of shock to inflation he is talking about, and I can imagine only two possibilities, either a nominal shock or a real shock.

Let’s say it’s a nominal shock. What kind of nominal shock might Cochrane have in mind? An increase in the money supply? Well, presumably an increase in the money supply would cause an increase in the price level, and a temporary increase in the rate of inflation, but if the increase in the money supply is a once-and-for-all increase, the system must revert, after a temporary increase, back to the old rate of inflation. Or maybe, Cochrane is thinking of a permanent increase in the rate of growth in the money supply. But in that case, why would the rate of inflation come back on its own as Cochrane suggests it would? Well, maybe it’s not the money supply but money demand that’s changing. But again, one would normally assume that an appropriate change in central-bank policy could cope with such a scenario and stabilize the rate of inflation.

Alright, then, let’s say it’s a real shock. Suppose some real event happens that raises the rate of inflation. Well, like what? A supply shock? That raises the rate of inflation, but since when is the standard view that the appropriate response by the central bank to a negative supply shock is to raise the interest-rate target? Perhaps Cochrane is talking about a real shock that reduces the real rate of interest. Well, in that case, the rate of inflation would certainly rise if the central bank maintained its nominal-interest-rate target, but the increase in inflation would not be temporary unless the real shock was temporary. If the real shock is temporary, it is not clear why the standard view would recommend that the central bank raise its target rate of interest. So, I am sorry, but I am still confused.

Now, the standard view that Cochrane is disputing is actually derived from Wicksell, and Wicksell’s cycle theory is in fact based on the assumption that the central bank keeps its target interest rate fixed while the natural rate fluctuates. (This, by the way, was also Hayek’s assumption in his first exposition of his theory in Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle.) When the natural rate rises above the central bank’s target rate, a cumulative inflationary process starts, because borrowing from the banking system to finance investment is profitable as long as the expected return on investment exceeds the interest rate on loans charged by the banks. (This is where Hayek departed from Wicksell, focusing on Cantillon Effects instead of price-level effects.) Cochrane avoids that messy scenario, as far as I can tell, by assuming that the initial position is one in which the Fisher equation holds with the nominal rate equal to the real plus the expected rate of inflation and with expected inflation equal to actual inflation, and then positing an (as far as I can tell) unexplained inflation shock, with no change to the real rate (meaning, in Cochrane’s terminology, that the economy is stable). If the unexplained inflation shock goes away, the system must return to its initial equilibrium with expected inflation equal to actual inflation and the nominal rate equal to the real rate plus inflation.

In contrast, the Wicksellian assumption is that the real rate fluctuates with the nominal rate and expected inflation unchanged. Unless the central bank raises the nominal rate, the difference between the profit rate anticipated by entrepreneurs and the rate at which they can borrow causes the rate of inflation to increase. So it does not seem to me that Cochrane has in any way reconciled the Neo-Fisherian view with the standard view (or at least the Wicksellian version of the standard view).

PS I would just note that I have explained in my paper on Ricardo and Thornton why the Wicksellian analysis (anticipated almost a century before Wicksell by Henry Thornton) is defective (basically because he failed to take into account the law of reflux), but Cochrane, as far as I can tell, seems to be making a completely different point in his discussion.

13 Responses to “John Cochrane Explains Neo-Fisherism”


  1. 1 CMA November 12, 2014 at 10:30 pm

    “What kind of nominal shock might Cochrane have in mind? An increase in the money supply? Well, presumably an increase in the money supply would cause an increase in the price level, and a temporary increase in the rate of inflation, but if the increase in the money supply is a once-and-for-all increase, the system must revert, after a temporary increase, back to the old rate of inflation.”

    But the system cant both revert to the old level of inflation and keep the same interest rate because to maintain that lower rate you need to increase the growth rate of money.

    Lowering the interest rate and maintaining it too low implies a permanent increase in the rate of growth of money. As you know the fed funds rate is affected adjusting the monetary base. Its constantly being pushed down by a higher rate of money growth.

    Like

  2. 2 Nick Rowe November 13, 2014 at 4:28 am

    Good post David.

    Two very minor points:

    1. “the most famous attempt (by the Fed after World War II) to peg an interest rate having led to accelerating inflation during the Korean War, thereby forcing the peg to be abandoned, in apparent contradiction of the Neo-Fisherian view.”

    And when the Fed abandoned the peg, it *raised* the rate of interest, right?

    2. “why the Wicksellian analysis (anticipated almost a century before Wicksell by Henry Thornton) is defective (basically because he failed to take into account the law of reflux), ”

    Thornton was presumably talking about a world where the gold standard provided a nominal peg. Was Wicksell also talking about a gold standard world?

    Like

  3. 3 Thomas Aubrey November 13, 2014 at 7:02 am

    “Unless the central bank raises the nominal rate, the difference between the profit rate anticipated by entrepreneurs and the rate at which they can borrow causes the rate of inflation to increase.”

    This isn’t necessarily the case. Ohlin argued that excess profits can be invested in financial assets which has a limited impact on the general price level. It’s also worth pointing out that Myrdal (as well as Hayek), following on from David Davidson’s criticisms of Wicksell argued that a stable price level was not compatible with parity of the two rates of interest due to the dynamic nature of productivity.

    Like

  4. 4 JW Mason November 13, 2014 at 8:56 am

    I think you are being a little unfair to Cochrane. I don’t read him as making the neo-Fisherian case, just thinking it through. In your summary, it sounds like he is saying “because the economy is stable, inflation will adjust in response to a permanent change in the interest rate,” which would be a bizarrely teleological thing to say. But what he seems to be saying is just, “If the economy is stable, then there must be some mechanism that causes the inflation rate to adjust to the interest rate.” But he seems agnostic about what that mechanism might be.

    By the way, it has always struck me as exceedingly strange that this position gets labeled as “neo-Fisherian.” After all, Fisher was the guy who wrote “The Debt Deflation of Great Depressions,” in which the divergent behavior of real interest rates plays a central role.

    Like

  5. 5 JW Mason November 13, 2014 at 8:58 am

    “Was Wicksell also talking about a gold standard world?”

    Presumably this question is rhetorical but just in case it’s not, the answer is No. Wicksell was talking about a world of pure credit money.

    Like

  6. 6 JP Koning November 13, 2014 at 10:48 am

    …and Thornton was writing during a period when the pound had been delinked from gold.

    As for 1951, the $US was pegged, so didn’t that anchor the price level?

    Like

  7. 7 JW Mason November 13, 2014 at 12:13 pm

    JP – good point re Thornton. You are right, the Restriction was the key context for his work.

    Woodford for what it’s worth thinks that pre Treasury-Fed accord, the price level was anchored by the expectation of future fiscal surpluses. WHich I thnk is silly, but at least he does address the question.

    Now one thing I will criticize Cochrane for is posing the question as, Is the economy stable. The economy is a complex system and includes both positive and negative feedback loops. The positive feedbacks are destabilizing, the negative ones obviously destabilizing. So to infer from the fact that prices as a whole are stable (or at least not too unstable) to the nonexistence of a particular positive feedback, seems completely unwarranted. It’s perfectly possible for the NK description of the behavior of real interest rates in the context of nominal interest rate peg to be correct, but for that positive feedback to be overpowered by a negative feedback somewhere else — say, by the fact that consumption demand becomes less elastic as current consumption falls, or the fact that gross investment cannot fall below zero, or by the trade balance, or by various other things. The implicit assumption that the central bank policy rule is the ONLY negative feedback seems unjustified.

    This is a concern I have about some of Nick’s stuff too. He thinks the fact that the positive inflation-interest rate feedback doesn’t run away, is strong evidence for his preferred negative feedback in the form of the real balance effect. But there are plenty of other possible stabilizing relationships.

    Like

  8. 8 David Glasner November 13, 2014 at 12:24 pm

    CMA, I don’t understand. A one-time increase in the money supply raises prices, but once the price level rises, nothing else has changed.

    You said:

    “the system cant both revert to the old level of inflation and keep the same interest rate because to maintain that lower rate you need to increase the growth rate of money.”

    What is the “lower rate” that you are referring to?

    Nick, Thanks.

    1 That’s right.

    2 As JP pointed out, Thornton was writing when the gold standard had been suspended during the Napoleonic Wars, but he was discussing both convertibility and inconvertibility at various points in his book. AS JW pointed out, Wicksell was discussing a pure credit economy, which is why the price level isn’t determined by the value of gold.

    Thomas, You are right, of course, but I was focusing on the simple Wicksellian model.

    JW, Cochrane is lucky to have you on his side.

    About the mechanism that causes the inflation rate to adjust to the interest rate, I think that we are all waiting to hear some explanation of how the mechanism works rather than just an invocation of the Fisher eqution. I agree that the Neo-Fisherian label is not very fair to Fisher, even more unfair than I was to Cochrane.

    JP, The gold peg in 1951 was a joke, because the only people allowed to demand gold from the Treasury were other central banks. On top of that the US could determine the value of gold by selling off some its huge reserves on the market.

    Like

  9. 9 Benjamin Cole November 14, 2014 at 6:01 am

    A couple observations: 1) I asked Cochrane if Volker had properly raised rates to fight inflation. Should have Volker lowered rates?

    Cochran says the Volcker era aas different and it made sense to raise rates then to fight inflation because Ronald Reagan’s budget was in deficit but not Ronald Reagan’s operating budget.

    Okay, from there we go to 2), is not an interest rate peg an attempt to price control credit? And how do government price controls usually work out?

    Like

  10. 10 Thornton Hall November 14, 2014 at 3:36 pm

    “Plausibility”? What is the role of “plausibility” in an empirical science?

    Like

  11. 11 CMA November 14, 2014 at 8:27 pm

    “CMA, I don’t understand. A one-time increase in the money supply raises prices, but once the price level rises, nothing else has changed.”

    You said:

    “the system cant both revert to the old level of inflation and keep the same interest rate because to maintain that lower rate you need to increase the growth rate of money.”

    What is the “lower rate” that you are referring to?”

    An increase in the money supply also reduces the FFR in the US system. A one time increase will send up inflation and higher inflation will place upward pressure on the FFR. A one time increase in money wont allow the FFR to stay at some specified level if inflation/growth picks up because after inflation hits the rate follows up. To keep the rate at its target once inflation increases it has to again do another injection of money and a cycle will continue.

    Like

  12. 12 JW Mason November 15, 2014 at 10:02 am

    “is not an interest rate peg an attempt to price control credit?”

    No it is not. Central bank buys and sells bonds in the open market. No price controls involved.

    Like

  13. 13 sumnerbentley November 15, 2014 at 5:29 pm

    David, Good post. In your comments you said that only foreign central banks could redeem dollars for gold in 1951. I had thought that was only true after 1968, and that until 1968 foreign individuals could also redeem dollars for gold. Is that not so?

    Like


Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.




About Me

David Glasner
Washington, DC

I am an economist in the Washington DC area. My research and writing has been mostly on monetary economics and policy and the history of economics. In my book Free Banking and Monetary Reform, I argued for a non-Monetarist non-Keynesian approach to monetary policy, based on a theory of a competitive supply of money. Over the years, I have become increasingly impressed by the similarities between my approach and that of R. G. Hawtrey and hope to bring Hawtrey’s unduly neglected contributions to the attention of a wider audience.

My new book Studies in the History of Monetary Theory: Controversies and Clarifications has been published by Palgrave Macmillan

Follow me on Twitter @david_glasner

Archives

Enter your email address to follow this blog and receive notifications of new posts by email.

Join 3,272 other subscribers
Follow Uneasy Money on WordPress.com