Lars Christensen on Market Monetarism

Lars Christensen, Chief Analyst at Danske Bank and a regular and valued commenter on this blog since it started over two months ago, has been following and participating in debates about monetary policy in the blogosphere for the past two or three years.  Drawing on his considerable expertise as a monetary economist, a wealth of hands-on knowledge of financial markets and monetary policy, and his comprehensive knowledge of what the blogosphere is saying about monetary policy, Lars has performed a huge public service in distilling some of the most significant results of those debates in his excellent working paper “Market Monetarism: The Second Monetarist Counterrevolution” posted on Marcus Nunes’s blog. The paper appeared while I was in Japan, so I am tardy in acknowledging Lars’s contribution and in offering some of my own thoughts on various points in his paper.  But better late than never.

In addition to doing a great job of extracting the key analytical and policy contributions from nearly three years of discussions about monetary policy in the blogosphere, Lars performs an equally valuable and impressive service in tracing and explaining the monetary- and macoreconomic-theoretic background of the blogosphere discussion. And besides summarizing the relevant theoretical background for market monetarism, Lars shows how the blogosphere discussion is already advancing traditional scholarship, suggesting that the contributions are likely to increase in significance as the interface between academic and blogosphere discussions widens and becomes increasingly permeable.

Lars’s piece reminds me of two other important survey articles introducing an emergent new literature in the context of both historical antecedents and opposing views: Milton Friedman’s 1956 restatement of the quantity theory and the introductory essay Harry Johnson and Jacob Frenkel wrote to their 1976 volume on the monetary approach to the balance of payments. It is far too early to tell how the story of market monetarism will play itself out, but if story turns out as many of us hope it will, Lars’s paper will likely be viewed as an early milestone.

Much of Lars’s survey focuses on the intellectual leader of market monetarism, Scott Sumner, whose influential blog (www.TheMoneyIllusion.com) was a catalyst in the formation and development of market monetarism and whose tireless blogging and relentless, but witty and good-natured, advocacy was critical in making market monetarism a force to be reckoned with in the blogosphere and, increasingly, in academic discourse. But Lars also gives due credit to other contributors like Nick Rowe (www.worthwhile.typepad.com), David Beckworth (www.macromarketmusings.blogsopt.com), Bill Woolsey (www.monetaryfreedom-billwoolsey.blogspot.com), and Josh Hendrickson (www.everydayeconomist.wordpress.com), while citing Robert Hetzel of the Richmond Federal Reserve Bank as a seminal figure and influence on Sumner and the others. Lars also mentions me and this blog as well as Marcus Nunes and his blog as “part of the bigger Market Monetarist family.”

I am happy to be included in this family, but the question has come up in various off-line exchanges (perhaps even in an earlier draft of Lars’s paper) whether I consider myself to be a Market Monetarist (or a quasi-Monetarist, as Paul Krugman has referred to Scott and company). Lars’s paper actually touches on certain theoretical issues about which I am inclined to disagree with my Market Monetarist colleagues, and I hope to have something to say about those issues in some future posts. I am certainly less a fan of Milton Friedman and old-fashioned Monetarism than they tend to be, so I am not all that eager to adopt a label suggesting that I am a follower Friedman and Monetarism. (I am afraid that may sound a bit too critical of Friedman, who was certainly a great economist, but I regard much of his work on money as seriously flawed and a long step backwards from the achievements of earlier monetary theorists, especially Hawtrey.) The labeling problem is that any view that holds that monetary policy is crucial to macroeconomic stability, even one based on non-Friedmanian sources, can legitimately be identified as Monetarist, however different the underlying theory of how monetary policy operates, or should operate, from Friedman’s.

Of course, this raises the question, debated already in a number of places, what exactly to call the school of monetary thought formerly known as a quasi-Monetarism. Lars has opted for Market Monetarism, and by the force of his reasoning, charm, personality, and good timing, it looks as if he just may carry the day. Scott Sumner actually sent me an email recently (I think I got it while I was in Japan), asking me what I thought about the different alternatives. Because of my (perhaps overly finicky) reservations about Monetarism, but perhaps also because of a temperamental reluctance to identify myself with any particular school of thought, I didn’t register a preference for any of the names. But as I have thought further about the various names I have belatedly decided that I favor neo-monetarism over Market Monetarism, quasi-Monetarism, or other candidates.

I concluded that Market Monetarism is not such a good choice, because, as others have already pointed out, it is not at all clear what adding “market” to “monetarism” is intended to signify. Presumably, Market Monetarists are supposed to be more sensitive to information generated by markets in formulating monetary policy than were traditional Monetarists who favored a mechanical, preset rule for controlling one or more monetary aggregates. Nevertheless, traditional Monetarism was hardly antagonistic toward markets and market-oriented economic policies, so the modifier “market” carries a certain invidious, though unintended, implication about traditional Monetarism. Even worse, the vagueness of the adjective “market” when used in connection with Monetarism calls to mind F. A. Hayek’s pointed remark about what happens when the adjective “social” is combined with any other term.

“Social” became more and more the description of the pre-eminent virtue, the attribute in which the good man excelled and the ideal by which communal action was to be guided. But while this development indefinitely extended the field of application of the term “social,” it did not give it the required new meaning. It even so much deprived it of its original descriptive meaning that American sociologists have found it necessary to coin the new term “societal” in its place. Indeed, it has produced a situation in which “social” can be used to describe almost any action as publicly desirable and has at the same time the effect of depriving any terms with which it is combined of clear meaning. Not only “social justice” but also “social democracy,” or “social market economy” or the “social state of law” . . . are expressions which, though justice, democracy, the market economy or the Rechstaat have by themselves perfectly good meanings, the addition of the adjective “social” makes them capable of meaning almost anything one likes. The word has indeed become one of the chief sources of confusion of political discourse and can probably no longer be reclaimed for a useful purpose.  (Law, Legislation and LIberty, vol. 2, pp. 79-80)

Do we really want the same fate to befall “market”?

So I would opt for neo-monetarism, which is not exactly descriptive except insofar as it suggests that there is some undefined difference between old Monetarism and new monetarism (to be distinguished from New Monetarism), just as the nature of the difference between classical and neo-classical economics is not evident from the labels. But classical and neo-classical economics are, indeed, very different theoretical constructs; one cannot discern the difference just from the name; one has to learn a little about each to see wherein the difference lies. In that sense, market monetarism tends to obscure, and perhaps mislead, rather than to inform, while neo-monetarism neither misleads nor misinforms. Anyway, that, for whatever it’s worth, is my take.

12 Responses to “Lars Christensen on Market Monetarism”


  1. 1 Lars Christensen September 21, 2011 at 7:57 am

    David, thanks for the extremely kind words about my paper. It is much appreciated.

    I will just let it sink in that you have compared my work with Friedman and Johnson/Frenkel…I don’t know what to say about that other than I am damn proud;-)

    Like

  2. 2 Lee Kelly September 21, 2011 at 9:23 am

    Chief Analysit?

    That’s actually quite funny. Does this mean that Lars is chief of sitting on his arse at Danske Bank?

    Also, the blogosphere brings together an eclectic bunch of people, does it not? Commenters on these blogs (and some of the best stuff is found in the comments) come from all over the map and from all age groups, including both amateurs and professionals. At what other time in history could an intellectual movement like market monetarism (or neo-monetarism, or whatever) actually happen? I count myself lucky to have such an opportunity to read and then discuss such interesting ideas with such accomplished people. Outside of the internet, my life has nothing to do with economics, and I know almost nobody who is even remotely interested in the problems which get addressed on blogs like this. Seriously, the economics blogosphere (particularly that of market monetarism) has greatly enriched my life and I am thankful for all the bloggers and commenters out there, like David and Lars, who continue to do such good work and make it so accessible to people like me.

    Like

  3. 3 Lee Kelly September 21, 2011 at 9:29 am

    David,

    I would say you sit somewhere on the periphery of market monetarism, kind of like George Selgin but for different reasons. That’s fine in my book. These labels never fit everyone perfectly. Oh, and I don’t worry about the term “market” — I don’t think it can be butchered of meaning much more than it has been already. I think there is also some intentional ambiguity in Lars’s use of the term, since “market” in “market monetarism” can be interpreted in subtlety different ways while still keeping to the same spirit.

    Like

  4. 4 Lars Christensen September 21, 2011 at 12:01 pm

    @ Lee, unfortunately I don’t sit on my A enough as I travel quite a bit, but you are clearly right about the MM movement – the blogosphere brings together eclectic bunch of people and I think there is some clear value in that. From my own perspective even though I think of myself as relatively academic type of economist I of course has a “market” background (as well as a bureaucrat background), which hopefully can bring a slightly different perspective on the discussion than if I had just been sitting in a university all my adult life.

    The eclectic approach is also in my view an disadvantage as I also think a more stringent perspective is needed basically to bring MM into the textbook. How dare challenge Mankiw to put MM into his next macro textbook?

    Like

  5. 5 David Glasner September 22, 2011 at 12:44 pm

    Lars, Just remember that I am not one of Friedman’s biggest fans.

    Lee, I seem to have been making a lot of typos lately, would you care to volunteer as my proof-reader? I appreciate greatly your kind words about the contribution that I and others are making to economic enlightenment. And you are probably right that I am a peripheral figure. But I can deal with that.

    Like

  6. 6 Benjamin Cole October 2, 2011 at 8:19 pm

    David-

    I hope you get on board with “market monetarism” for practical reasons. If each of us describe and stand by our minor differences, then market monetarism will be nothing more than people reading each other’s blogs, along with a few fans like myself.

    Lars has come up with a very good name for an aggressive, confident Fed policy that targets nominal GDP. That is what the the United States and Europe need now.

    If in broad terms you subscribe to that idea (and I think you do) then salute and get in line, or lead, but don’t pollywoodle. I just made that word up, but I kind of like it. Okay, blood pressure coming down now….

    Like

  7. 7 David Glasner October 3, 2011 at 6:44 pm

    Benjamin, Don’t worry, I am on board, but that shouldn’t prevent me from voicing my opinion. There is too much libertarianism (definitely small “l” by the way) among us to expect us not to express our views if we disagree with each other. Without differences of opinion life would be really boring. Glad your blood pressure came down.

    Like


  1. 1 Browsing Catharsis – 09.22.11 « Increasing Marginal Utility Trackback on September 22, 2011 at 5:03 am
  2. 2 MM « Everyday, it's all right! Trackback on October 18, 2011 at 1:47 am
  3. 3 マーケット・マネタリズムにおけるラルス・クリステンセン by デーヴィッド・グラスナー – 道草 Trackback on October 19, 2011 at 6:10 am
  4. 4 マーケット・マネタリズム 第二のマネタリスト反革命(本文) by ラルス・クリステンセン – 道草 Trackback on October 19, 2011 at 6:48 am
  5. 5 Danton | Ecco i bookmarket dell’Economist Trackback on March 14, 2014 at 12:19 pm

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.




About Me

David Glasner
Washington, DC

I am an economist in the Washington DC area. My research and writing has been mostly on monetary economics and policy and the history of economics. In my book Free Banking and Monetary Reform, I argued for a non-Monetarist non-Keynesian approach to monetary policy, based on a theory of a competitive supply of money. Over the years, I have become increasingly impressed by the similarities between my approach and that of R. G. Hawtrey and hope to bring Hawtrey’s unduly neglected contributions to the attention of a wider audience.

My new book Studies in the History of Monetary Theory: Controversies and Clarifications has been published by Palgrave Macmillan

Follow me on Twitter @david_glasner

Archives

Enter your email address to follow this blog and receive notifications of new posts by email.

Join 3,270 other subscribers
Follow Uneasy Money on WordPress.com